WHAT
ECONOMISTS NEVER TOLD US:
THE
ELUSIVE SOLUTION TO
HIGH
PUBLIC SERVICE RATES
All of my writings,
all of my recommendations, all government reforms that have to be undertaken
towards reduction of our unduly high public service rates, have to culminate in
what I wrap up in this paper. If there is a “magic formula” towards reasonable
power, water, telecom, toll-road, and other service rates in captive markets
attended to by public interest, this is it.
PART
I
THE
CASE FOR REGULATION
OF
CAPTIVE MARKETS CLOTHED
WITH
PUBLIC INTEREST
OBSERVE THAT ALL OF OUR HIGH POWER,
WATER, TELECOM, AND TOLL-ROAD RATES
ARE ROOTED FROM A COMMON DENOMINATOR:
LACK OF ENFORCED SAFETY NET AGAINST
OVERPRICING: RATE-OF-RETURN LIMIT
THE SOLUTION THEN TO OUR UNDULY HIGH
PUBLIC SERVICE RATES IS ENFORCEMENT
OF REASONABLE RATE-OF-RETURN CEILING
TO BEGIN
WITH,
THE BASIC
PREMISE OF DEMOCRATIC GOVERNANCE:
THE GREATEST
GOOD FOR THE GREATEST NUMBER
Under Article II of the Constitution:
“The Philippines is a democratic and republican state. Sovereignty resides in
the people and all government authority emanates from them…. The prime duty of
government is to serve and protect the people.”
In effect, our Constitution and laws
have adopted the majority rule as normal basis of decision making, with simple
majority of one or two-thirds majority as winning vote on crucial issues. In essence, majority
rule translates to the greatest
good for the greatest number
under democratic governance.
Free-market
Economists have Ignored
the Greatest
Good for the Greatest Number
in the
Privatization of—or Awarding of
Franchises
in—Captive
Markets Clothed with Public Interest,
Thereby
Resulting in Unduly High Public Service Rates
Our very high public service rates, which stick out
like a sore thumb in Asia, is an economic problem that has victimized not only
big and small businesses but also generally poor consumers and commuters
nationwide. We have abnormally high power, water, telecom, and toll-road rates
in the region. We also have very high medicine and agro-chemical prices. For
example, our second highest power rates in Asia (next only to those in Japan)
have for so long served as heavy burden to business and stumbling block to our
rapid industrialization and faster economic growth.
THE ROOT AND COMMON
DENOMINATOR
OF OUR VERY HIGH PUBLIC
SERVICE RATES:
LACK OF ENFORCED
RATE-OF-RETURN CEILING
ON ALL—REPEAT ALL—PUBLIC
SERVICE PROVIDERS!
HOW THIS CAME ABOUT IS
UNFLATTERING TO
THE PHILIPPINE ECONOMICS
“PROFESSION”
There is a common denominator or cause of our unwarrantedly
high public service rates in the power, water, telecom, toll-road, and probably
other public service industries that cater to mass consumers and commuters—lack
of properly enforced rate-of-return limit on government authorized public
service providers. Obviously,
if there is an effectively implemented
profit-rate ceiling, EVEN IF THERE IS NO COMPETITION, public service rates
cannot go beyond reasonable levels—this is basic and plain common sense.
Conversely, even if there are competing oligopolistic
public service providers, if there is no
prescribed profit-rate limit, cartelized operation or regulatory capture can
easily nullify the price-lowering effect of competition.
Root of Lack of Enforced
Rate-of-Return Limit:
Products of Local and
Foreign Top Universities—
Dominant Free-Market
Economists Unskilled in the Fine
Points of Properly Managing
the Two Types of Market:
(1) the Really Free Market for Thousands of
Ordinary Goods
and Services, and (2) the
Captive Markets for Relatively Few
Basic Necessities Clothed with Public
Interest, to Which
the Power, Water, Telecom,
and Toll-Road Markets Belong
From management audit standpoint, the Philippine
economics “profession” has failed to help the government shape national
economic policies and practices that spur economic development, promote
equality and inclusive growth, maintain a fair balance between the conflicting
interests of business and consumers, and bridge the gap between the poor and
the rich.
Our abnormally high power rates, for example, have
long served as obstacle to our industrialization and fast economic growth, yet
our economists in and out of government have not offered the readily available
solution that will definitely bring down our country’s second highest power
rates in the region to reasonable level—strict enforcement of the
Supreme-Court-ruled 12% rate-of-return limit, to be calculated based on net income before income tax (ERB vs. Meralco, G.R.
No. 141314, November 15, 2002).
As explained further later, Meralco’s return on equity (ROE) as of 2015 stood at 31% before income tax and 24% after income tax, in violation of the Supreme Court
ruling either way we look at it. Under the situation,
if Meralco’s rate of return is adjusted downward to 12% as required by
jurisprudence, its rates will definitely go down, so why is the Philippine
economics “profession” deafeningly silent on it, despite my repeated emails to
key members of it in the past?
Thus, our high public service rates are caused by lack
of properly enforced rate-of-return
ceiling, rooted in turn from the failure
of the academe in the Philippines and abroad to produce Filipino economists who can
distinguish between—and treat differently—the two types of market: the really free market for ordinary goods and services and captive market for basic
necessities clothed with public interest. This problem stems from the dominance
of free-market economists in the academe. They do not teach the fine points and
applicability to crucial captive markets of regulation—probably because they
are biased against it, they themselves were not taught about it in their
student days in business schools, they are inexperienced on it, and they are
simply not experts on it.
The past oil industry regulation was conceptualized
by one of my former immediate bosses, then Bureau of Energy Utilization
Director Orlando L. Galang, a chemical engineer—not an economist—and alumnus of
Texas A & M University, Under it, oil prices were limited to those that
will yield rock bottom peso profit per liter of petroleum products sold. From
it, I learned to appreciate the need for regulation in captive markets affected
with public interest. I
improved on what I saw in the past by espousing not peso-per-unit profit
limit but percent
rate-of-return ceiling. To my recollection, the oil industry—or at least Petron Corporation
where I served as Controller before changing career to become a modest
entrepreneur—was then earning way less than 8% return on equity. Now, under
deregulation, we do not even know what rate of return the oil industry is
earning, or whether it engages in overpricing or not—definitely not the proper
way to manage the economy.
What Competition as
Price-Lowering Economic Tool
Has Failed to Do Indirectly in Deregulated WESM under
Fallacious EPIRA (RA
9136)—Bring Down High Power Rates—
Regulation with Proper
Enforcement of Rate-of-Return Limit
Will Do Directly in the Power Generation
Industry, and Such
Regulation Applies to Other
Crucial Captive Markets as Well
“Economists firmly
believe that voluntary transactions in free markets tend to work toward the
common good. But they also believe that nearly every participant in the market place would love
to rig the system in his or her own favor.” [Sean Masaki
Flynn, Economics for Dummies (NJ: Wiley Publishing,
Inc., 2005) p. 334]
Therefore, instituting free-market COMPETITION under DEREGULATION
does not always mean low prices, because profit-maximizing market players will instinctively
work for more profits for as long as they can, as in the case especially of our
ultra high medicine prices before the passage of the Cheaper Medicine Act in
2008 (RA 9502).
As part of human nature and rapacious greed, despite presence of
numerous suppliers, free market can yield high prices to the extent the
MARKET CAN BEAR—without regard
to actual low cost of goods sold by the
competing market players, an advantage that they keep to themselves and
do not share as price reduction to consumers—for as long as there is opportunity
for “every participant in the market place... to rig the
system in his or her own favor.”
The government should be proactive, not reactive. It should plug
vulnerabilities to, or opportunity for, market rigging. It should promptly
institute the safety net against
already existing—not just impending—unreasonable rates in the power, water,
telecom, and probably other crucial captive markets: reasonable
cap in rate of return.
Why Regulation of Captive Markets
Will Not be Unfair to Public Service
Providers:
They Will Not be Forced Against their
Will to Serve,
They Will Serve the Captive Markets, With
Sure Demand
From Mass Consumers, Under Regulation Rules
Set by
the Government Because it is Still More
Profitable
for them to Do So Compared to Available
Alternatives
In affirming its landmark decision that disallowed deduction from
net income of corporate income tax in the reckoning of Meralco’s entitlement to
12% reasonable return (ERB vs. Meralco, G.R. No. 141314, November 15, 2002),
upon Meralco’s appeal, the Supreme Court ruled further, as follows:
“The business and operations of a public
utility are imbued with public interest. In a very real sense, a public utility
is engaged in public service—providing basic commodities and services
indispensable to the interest of the general public. For this reason, a public utility submits to the regulation of government
authorities and surrenders certain business prerogatives, including the amount
of rates that may be charged by it.” (Republic of the Philippines, represented by Energy Regulatory
Board vs. Manila Electric Company, G.R. No. 141314, April, 9, 2003).
Therefore, in the privatization
of government public-utility operations and awarding of franchises to public
service companies, like those in the power, water, telecom, and toll-road
industries, the government should set
franchise or concession conditions protective of consumers and commuters, such
as 12% or lower rate-of-return ceiling.
For as long as there are takers—which means that the
government franchise or concession conditions are still more advantageous to
private investors compared to their opportunity cost, the government should
stick to those conditions. Only if there are no takers should the government sweeten
the pot to attract investors.
THE FUNDAMENTAL SOLUTION
TO OUR UNDULY HIGH PUBLIC
SERVICE RATES
THAT HAS ELUDED FOR SO LONG
OUR HIGHLY
EDUCATED ECONOMISTS AND
FINANCE EXPERTS
IN AND OUT OF GOVERNMENT AND
ACADEME:
PROPER ENFORCEMENT OF
RATE-OF-RETURN
CEILING TO PUBLIC SERVICE
PROVIDERS—
THE SAFETY NET AGAINST
OVERPRICING
There is a basic and common-sense solution that has
been lacking and has seemingly eluded even our reputable economic and finance experts—proper
enforcement of reasonable rate-of-return ceiling, which currently
stands at 12% for public utility monopolies, as ruled by the Supreme
Court in 1966 and reiterated in 2002 (ERB vs. Meralco, G.R. No. 141314,
November 15, 2002). The lack of enforced rate-of-return
ceiling stems from the following:
1. Lack of proper
regulation of oligopolies in captive markets
affected with public interest, such as those in the telecom industry, followed by those in the power generation
industry which have been deregulated under the Electric Power Industry Reform
Act (EPIRA) of 2001 (RA 9136).
2. Lack of proper
regulation of even the monopolies already subject to
regulation pursuant to Section 19, Article XII of the Constitution—those
operating in captive markets for public services clothed with public interest,
such as in the power, water, and toll-road industries.
Following are the key performance indicators of lack of proper regulation of monopolies Meralco and Maynilad Water: their excessively high rates of
return on equity (ROE) based on their annual financial reports to stockholders
and Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC):
Meralco ROE: Maynilad ROE:
2011: 20% 2008: 247%
2012: 25% 2009: 147%
2013: 23% 2010: 82%
2014: 23% 2011: 59%
2015: 24% 2012: 44%
The foregoing rates of ROE were calculated based on
the conventional method of reckoning profit:
net income AFTER income tax. In the case of
Meralco, if the rate of return is determined based on the Supreme Court ruling
that disallowed INCOME TAX deduction in the reckoning of 12% reasonable rate of
return, Meralco’s ROE based on net income BEFORE income
tax is a whopping
31% in 2015! Is the Supreme Court ruling a joke that ERC and
Meralco can make a mockery of it and violate it with impunity?
PART II
HOW TO INSTITUTE PROPER
REGULATION OF CAPTIVE
MARKETS
IMBUED WITH PUBLIC INTEREST
HOW TO ENFORCE
RATE-OF-RETURN LIMIT
UNDER PROPER REGULATION OF
MONOPOLIES
AND OLIGOPOLIES IN CAPTIVE
MARKETS FOR BASIC
NECESSITIES AFFECTED WITH
PUBLIC INTEREST
Under a system of fair and justifiable regulation, reasonable rate-of-return limit can—and should—be applied to all monopolistic and
oligopolistic public service
providers in captive markets clothed with public interest, including the
power-generator oligopoly deregulated under EPIRA (RA 9136).
As Change for the Better
Under Privatization, Private Power
Generators
Should be Subject to 12% Reasonable
Return Limit
Allowed to Monopolies, or Preferably
Lower; Allowing
them Higher Rate of Return Will Make
Privatization
a Change from Bad to Worse, Not Change
for the Better
If regulated
monopolies like public utilities are entitled to 12% maximum return on
investment (ROI) under a 1966 Supreme Court ruling on Meralco, reiterated in
its landmark decision on Meralco corporate income tax (ERB vs, Meralco, G.R.
NO. 141314, November 15, 2002), then as change for the better under
EPIRA-mandated privatization, competing deregulated private generators should
be entitled to less than 12% ROI, or at most equal to it, otherwise the change
will be from bad to worse.
Privatization in the power
generation
industry is a shift from regulated government monopoly without competition—the
power-generator National Power Corporation (NAPOCOR)—to deregulated private
oligopoly with supposed competition. It is intended to be a change for the
better, from a monopoly without competitors to oligopoly with price-lowering
competition.
If so, as key
performance indicator (KPI) of the change for the better, as regulated
monopolies NAPOCOR and Meralco, as well as other public utility monopolies, are
entitled to maximum 12% return on investment as ruled by the Supreme Court (ERB
vs. Meralco, G.R. No. 141314, November 15, 2002), then—as proof of change for
the better—the private oligopoly with competition
should be entitled to return on investment lower than, or at most equal to, the
12% rate-of-return ceiling for the cited monopolies without
competition—otherwise what is privatization with competition for?
No comments:
Post a Comment